In November of 2002, I wrote �Uprooting
the Root Cause of Famine in Ethiopia,� a sequel to an article entitled
�The Paradox of Bread Basket Starving Ethiopia� (September 2002),
which, in turn, is an outgrowth of a major project (The Politics of
Famine and Strategies For Development in Ethiopia) completed in
1988-90.
The main themes of the above titles
were galvanized in �Famine Could be Defeated Through a Synergy of
Development Programs,� that I have presented in December 2002. In all
the articles and the dissertation, �development� is thematic
centrality, as I shall presently reiterate in this article.
The focus of this article is on
population explosion as the culprit behind the Ethiopian famine, as some
neo-Malthusian observers like to argue. Population explosion, as will be
substantiated later, is not the main cause for the Ethiopian famine; lack
of development is. There is no doubt that population explosion, as a
factor, can aggravate other problems in the complex scenario of famine,
but to argue it is the main problem is tantamount to dismissing the
multivariate variables (ill-conceived government policy, instability,
unsustainable resource consumption, inappropriate and inadequate
technology, access to capital, inequity in land and other resources etc.)
that are the collective omen haunting the Ethiopian landscape.
We should have a deep and
comprehensive understanding of famine and the situation in Ethiopia in
order not to err in policy and come up with wrong prescription. It is for
this simple reason that I have argued in �Uprooting the Root Causes��
as stated below:
�In order to have clarity on the
phenomenon of famine, we must first be able to combat ambiguous,
elliptical, and seductive explanations of the Ethiopian famine. Put
otherwise, we must avoid sentimental and superficial analysis of mass
starvation shrouded in mystery and religious overtone.�
Once we establish a modicum of clarity
on the nature and causes of famine, we can easily discern the controversy
of population explosion, especially as pictured by the gloomiest
neo-Malthusian advocates.
When Thomas Malthus wrote his Essay
on the Principle of Population in 1798, he alarmed the world with an
Armageddon of human devastation, because he believed that the world
population was pushing against the earth�s resources. His simple, but
unscientific, logical deduction is that population increases in a
geometric and exponential ratio (1 to 2, 2 to 4, 4 to 8 et.) whereas food
production increases in only arithmetic ratio (1 to 2, 2 to 3, 3 to 4
etc.).
To be sure, the dramatic increase in
world population in the 20th century is unprecedented. As the World
Population Growth, 1750 to 1995 and Projected to 2050 of the United
Nations (1995) indicates, it took 2 million years for the world population
to reach 1 billion in 1804. In 1927, the world population was 2 billion; 3
billion in 1960, 4 billion in 1974, 5 billion in 1987, and before the turn
of the 21st century, it is in excess of 6 billion. Yes, Malthus is right
in this regard, but absolutely wrong in his prediction of food production.
The latter indeed has exhibited exponential, and hence surplus production.
What Malthus was unable to see and
predict was the revolutionary dynamic and mass production potential of the
Industrial Revolution that began in England in the 1750s. Ironically, he
was born and raised in England when the Industrial Revolution unleashed a
momentum unprecedented in human history. All societies that have witnessed
surplus production have escaped the vagaries of famine. The cause for
famine, therefore, is subsistence and fragile economy and not population.
On top of mass and surplus production,
distribution of wealth among members of society (we may not realize
equality, but we may come close to attaining equity), a critical political
economy tenet, is crucial in our extrapolation of the causes of famine.
The distribution of wealth may be controversial, but the exponential
growth of food production is indisputable. For example, American
agro-business giants like Archer Daniel Midland (ADM), Pioneer Hi-Bread,
and Monsanto, alone can feed the entire planet. I like to further
substantiate the thesis of lack of equity in wealth or lack of access to
food as the main culprit behind widespread famine.
According to a microeconomic
principle, popularly known as Engel�s Law, the ability to acquire more
food depends on the income necessary to buy it. Discussing �poverty and
entitlements� Amartya Sen argued that �starvation is the
characteristic of some people not having enough food to eat. It is not the
characteristic of being not enough to eat. While the latter can be the
cause of the former, it is but one of many possible causes.� By the same
token, Richard Barnet, in his book The Lean Years, quite convincingly,
tells us that �most people who stop eating do so not because there is
insufficient food grown in the world but because they no longer grow it
themselves and do not have the money to buy it.�
I have forwarded a similar line of
reasoning to that of Barnet�s in �The Paradox of Bread Basket Starving
Ethiopia.� Based on the data provided by Professor Michel Chossudovsky
(University of Ottawa), I have delineated Ethiopia�s rather ironic
inability to feed its famine stricken people despite surplus production.
But because most Ethiopian observers were mesmerized by the walking
skeletons and unable to assess the food production, I am again compelled
to reiterate the data and argument as shown below:
�Ethiopia produces more than 90% of
its consumption needs,� argues Chossudovsky, and �yet at the height of
the crisis the nationwide food deficit was estimated by the Food
Agricultural Organization (FAO) at 764,000 metric tons of grain
representing a shortfall of 13 kilos per person per annum. In Amhara,
grain production (1999-2000) was twenty percent in excess of consumption
needs. Yet 2.8 million in Amhara (representing 17% of the regions
population) became locked into famine zones and are �at risk�
according to the FAO.� By the same token, despite 600 million tons of
surplus in the Oromiya region, the latter was classified �at risk�
too.
In the final analysis, it is
underdevelopment coupled by inequity, not overpopulation, which is the
cause for food deficit and ultimately for mass starvation. When I say
overpopulation is not a problem, I don�t mean to dismiss entirely its
impact on the environment. It is quite apparent that overpopulation could
have an adverse effect on the farming and pasture areas. I also have no
violent objection to family planning to countercheck fertility rate.
However, my argument resonates the very weakness of the neo-Malthusian
demographic experts in family planning. Even if we manage to
systematically curb population growth by limiting family size, we may
still encounter famine unless and until we implement a sound and
comprehensive development agenda. Hence, the title of this article, �Development
is the Best Contraceptive.� I will further discuss the genesis and
messages of the title later; for now, I like to draw the attention of the
reader to the positions of neo-Malthusians and cornucopians on the
controversy of population explosion.
In 1995, Ronald Bailey edited and
published a very important book entitled The True State of the Planet.
One of the contributors, Nicholas Eberstadt, writes �Population, Food
and Income: Global Trends in the Twentieth Century.� Eberstadt presents
a cornucopian (growth optimist) and compelling analysis as opposed to the
neo-Malthusian growth pessimist stance:
Rapid population growth has
occurred not because human beings suddenly started breeding like
rabbits but because they finally stopped dropping like flies.
Despite a tripling of the world�s
population in this century, global health and productivity have
exploded. Today human beings eat better, produce more, and consume
more than ever.
�Overpopulation� is a problem
that has been misidentified and misdefined. The term has no scientific
definition or clear meaning. The problems typically associated with
overpopulation (hungry families, squalid and overcrowded living
conditions) are more properly understood as issues of poverty.
Although some blame dwindling
natural resources for the reversals and catastrophes that have
recently befallen heavily populated low-income countries, such
episodes are directly traceable to the policies or practices of
presiding governments.
On top of the above note, cornucopians
emphasize on the promise of the Green Revolution and attendant scientific
advances in agriculture since the 1950s known for its abundant yields. In
point of fact, Ethiopia also had a similar experience to that of India,
Indonesia and the Philippines in mechanized agriculture in the early 1960s
although the latter were mostly cash crop industry and at a much lower
scale.
By contrast, neo-Malthusians are
concerned by what they call ecological overshoot, referring to the earth�s
limited carrying capacity. Contrary to the pessimists, growth optimists
advance �sustainable development,� a catch phrase that has now
dominated international institutions, development agencies, and the
academia. Sustainable development is defined as �economic growth
engineered by policies that do not destroy the environment to subsidize
quick development and short-term profits for producers. Central to
sustainable development is that �the present generation�s needs must
be met without compromising the ability of future generations to meet
theirs.�
If we clearly understand the essence
of sustainable development, the message conveyed is that there is no
straightforward relationship between population growth and environmental
stress. Underdevelopment and poverty, on the other hand, directly affect
the environment. We can support this evidence by the Ethiopian experience
where the peasants unwittingly search for fuel wood as a major source of
energy, and inadvertently deplete the forest areas. Had the Ethiopian
peasants have the fortunes of utilizing alternative energies such as gas
and electricity, the forests would have been preserved; and had the
Ethiopian government and people implemented a massive reforestation
program, the Ethiopian green belt would have been replenished.
Before I conclude, I will briefly
touch upon conferences and policies on population. The first world
population conference that took place in Bucharest in 1974 prescribed
policies that gave weight to economic development and not birth control.
Delegates from the South appealed to the developed nations from the North
for assistance in development, and they have clearly stated that once
massive development programs are initiated, population control will take
its own course. In fact, the then prevailing view was enchanted by the
slogan development is the best contraceptive, which has become a
source of inspiration for my present writing.
The second world population conference
took place in Mexico City in 1984. Then, the dominant prevailing view was
�family planning,� although highly developed countries like the United
States advanced the idea of �free market principles should take
precedence over population matters� and also promote �resource saving
innovations in response to shortages created by population growth, so that
population growth is a stimulus, not a deterrent, to economic development,�
as amplified by political scientists Charles Kegley and Eugene Whittkopf.
When the third world population
conference met in Cairo in 1994, the Bucharest slogan of �development is
the best contraceptive� was revisited, but this conference attempted to
reconcile development and population control perspectives with much
emphasis on development. The title of the conference was self-explanatory:
International Conference on Population and Development (ICPD). The Cairo
conference clearly stated that �population stabilization can be achieved
only in the larger context of human development and sustainable economic
growth,� and this is what I want to convey in this article.
|